In order to have a better understanding of all the nuances of
discussing tax policy, I’m going to spend some time talking about terms that
policy wonks and lawmakers throw around a lot. This entry will focus on the
concept of elasticity; if you’re an economist this might be old news but a
refresher never hurts right?
So what is elasticity?
Basically, elasticity is a measure of responsiveness. It tells how much
one thing changes when you change something else that affects it. Best analogy is a rubber band; it’s elastic
when it stretches in response to you pulling it. In economics, there is elastic demand—this
happens when a consumer buys less of something when the price increases and
more of something when the price drops.
There’s also inelastic demand, which occurs when a consumer buys about
the same amount if the price goes up or down. Dr. Samuel Baker from the
University of South Carolina created an interactive tool that provides more examples of this concept. The first example he
provides is about a bleeding unconscious man that’s brought to an emergency
room. This would be considered inelastic
since he’ll get treatment regardless of the price.
So what does this have to do with tax policy? Lawmakers always have to consider how much of
a burden they’re imposing when raising taxes and know who actually ends up
paying for a tax that might be aimed a different group (example: buyer vs.
seller). This concept is know as tax incidence
If a tax is raised too much, use of the taxed service or product could
decrease below the expected level of tax revenue a government is aiming to
collect. Also, politicians need to be
aware of how the public will react to certain taxes. For example, food is pretty inelastic since
we need it to survive. If groceries were taxed in Washington, consumption might
decrease some but the tax will be paid due to the necessity of eating. This
would be a burden on families, especially those with lower incomes (Link to Catherine’s food brief).
Also, policymakers use the concept of elasticity to reduce certain
behaviors. The best example of this is tobacco (link to Catherine’s tobacco brief). It’s commonly known that the long-term
effects of smoking and chewing tobacco physically harm and kill people. This makes tobacco an easy target in terms of
raising taxes. To change consumption behavior, lawmakers raise the tax to try
and make smoking too expensive for consumers.
When this happens, revenue from
the tax declines and it’s easy for the Legislature to argue in favor of the
declining revenue of tobacco sales because the decreased use offsets future
healthcare costs. As Catherine mentioned, the State
recently closed a loophole for consumers when they raised the fee for
roll-your-own cigarettes.
That’s elasticity in a nutshell!
Without using mathematical models to describe pricing points and such,
just know that elasticity is how you react to certain things like cost and how
flexible you are when market variables change.
This is a relationship that government needs to understand well if it
wants to implement tax policies that are a) fair to the majority of citizens,
and b) politically possible. We’ll add
more definitions like this one to give you a clearer perspective of underlying
issues that come up when folks talk about taxes.
No comments:
Post a Comment